Sunday, September 30, 2007

Finding the Right Precedent

Harold James, the financial historian, looks back for historical parallels to the current financial turmoil. His bottom line:

If today’s credit crunch has historical parallels, they are closer to nineteenth-century “normal crises” like 1837, 1847, or 1857. In those panics, financial innovation caused uncertainty and nervousness, but also induced an important and beneficial learning process. The financial institutions that survived the crises went on to play a crucial role in pushing further development, and they had enhanced reputations because they withstood a crisis.

Sometimes monetary and fiscal authorities have an obligation to ignore the wilder historical parallels and look at a broader picture. Sometimes, too, the best response to a crisis is this: don’t just do something; stand there and do nothing.

James, incidentally, once coauthored work on financial crises with some guy named Ben Bernanke.

The Rationality of Harry Markowitz

A cute story about a great financial economist:
There is a story in the book about Harry Markowitz,” Mr. Zweig said the other day. He was referring to Harry M. Markowitz, the renowned economist who shared a Nobel for helping found modern portfolio theory — and proving the importance of diversification. It’s a story that says everything about how most of us act when it comes to investing. Mr. Markowitz was then working at the RAND Corporation and trying to figure out how to allocate his retirement account. He knew what he should do: “I should have computed the historical co-variances of the asset classes and drawn an efficient frontier.” (That’s efficient-market talk for draining as much risk as possible out of his portfolio.)



But, he said, “I visualized my grief if the stock market went way up and I wasn’t in it — or if it went way down and I was completely in it. So I split my contributions 50/50 between stocks and bonds.” As Mr. Zweig notes dryly, Mr. Markowitz had proved “incapable of applying” his breakthrough theory to his own money. Economists in his day believed powerfully in the concept of “economic man”— the theory that people always acted in their own best self-interest. Yet Mr. Markowitz, famous economist though he was, was clearly not an example of economic man.

 
I don't claim to be any better at asset allocation than Markowitz was. I take some comfort in the fact that I am not too far from the recommendations of David Swensen.

On the Ethics of Advising

A book review in the NY Times contains this thought-provoking passage on Milton Friedman:

Friedman’s association with Gen. Augusto Pinochet, the Chilean dictator, was indeed the worst stain on his career. His defense that his economic advice to Pinochet was no different from what a doctor might give a government on how to deal with an outbreak of AIDS is not very persuasive.
The problem is that the reviewer fails to then explain why it's not persuasive. He seems to assume that the explanation is obvious. But to me, it is not obvious at all.

Here is the basic problem. You are an expert working at an American university. A dictator calls you up, says his nation is facing a problem, and wants your help solving it. Many people, not just the dictator, are suffering because of this problem. What do you do? Does it matter whether the problem is an economic problem or a medical problem? If so, why? (If you want my opinion, here it is: I have no idea. Fortunately, I have never gotten any calls from dictators.)

[As an update, let me be more pointed: You are a professor at Harvard Medical School and the world's expert of deadly disease X. The head of a nation experiencing an epidemic of a new disease similar to X calls you for advice. You know how to make a cheap vaccine for this new disease, and you are the only person in the world with this knowledge. Do you offer the secret recipe unconditionally? If not, what conditions have to be met? If the nation head is a tyrannical dictator, would you refuse to help, knowing that letting the epidemic run its course might cause more suffering than the dictator ever did?]

Similar, but somewhat less emotionally charged, ethical issues arise in the context of advising democratically elected leaders. For two years, I worked as an adviser to George Bush. Now I am an occasional, unpaid adviser to Mitt Romney. To my constant surprise, some letter writers and some commenters on this blog presume that I must agree with, or be responsible for, every position they take. That is a deeply silly assumption.

Presidents and candidates have to make decisions on a multitude of issues. It is unreasonable to expect any adviser to agree on every single issue. Indeed, politicians listen to many advisers with different points of view. An adviser cannot resign in protest every time a decision fails to go the way he advised. The system could not function if people acted in such a self-centered way.

Consider: Should an economist who believes abortion is murder refuse to advise Barack Obama on tax reform? If this economist chooses to become an Obama adviser and Obama wins, is she then complicit in all the abortions that result from President Obama's pro-choice policies? If her advice on tax reform is only partially followed, should she resign her position as adviser? If she continues as an Obama adviser, is she then responsible for all policy positions that Obama takes? Is she even responsible for Obama's tax-reform proposal?

My answers are NO, NO, NO, NO, and NO. In my view, the adviser is responsible for the advice she gives, and Obama is responsible for the positions he takes.

Maybe I am being too easy on economic advisers, like Milton Friedman, myself, and my hypothetical Obama adviser. But I worry about what happens when sanctimony leads people to put too high of a moral "tax" on advisers from academia. Most academics avoid politics altogether, preferring the relative comfort and better compensation of life in the ivory tower. The uglier the world of politics becomes, the fewer academics will venture forth with their input, and the poorer everyone will be as a result.

Blinder on the Mortgage Mess


Princeton economist Alan Blinder writes about Six Fingers of Blame in the Mortgage Mess.

Saturday, September 29, 2007

Good News about Marriage

In today's NY Times, economists Betsey Stevenson and Justin Wolfers correct the record:

THE great myth about divorce is that marital breakup is an increasing threat to American families, with each generation finding their marriages less stable than those of their parents....The story of ever-increasing divorce is a powerful narrative. It is also wrong. In fact, the divorce rate has been falling continuously over the past quarter-century, and is now at its lowest level since 1970....

Why were so many analysts led astray by the recent data? Understanding this puzzle requires digging deeper into some rather complex statistics.

The Census Bureau reported that slightly more than half of all marriages occurring between 1975 and 1979 had not made it to their 25th anniversary.... But here’s the rub: The census data come from a survey conducted in mid-2004, and at that time, it had not yet been 25 years since the wedding day of around 1 in 10 of those whose marriages they surveyed....

The narrative of rising divorce is also completely at odds with counts of divorce certificates, which show the divorce rate as having peaked at 22.8 divorces per 1,000 married couples in 1979 and to have fallen by 2005 to 16.7.

Why has the great divorce myth persisted so powerfully? Reporting on our families is a lot like reporting on the economy: statistical tales of woe provide the foundation for reform proposals.

This seems to be an example of what Bryan Caplan calls " the pessimistic bias, a tendency to overestimate the severity of economic problems and underestimate the economy’s performance in the recent past, the present, and the future."

Behavioral Macroeconomics

The Boston Federal Reserve Bank is aiming to become the regional Fed that emphasizes behavioral economics (the oddly named subfield that emphasizes the intersection of economics and psychology). This past week, I attended a conference there on the topic.

Here is Janet Yellen's talk at the conference on "Implications of Behavioral Economics for Monetary Policy." (Thanks to Mark Thoma for the link.)

Friday, September 28, 2007

A New Entitlement?

The big problem with U.S. fiscal policy is that, over the years, politicians of both parties have voted for unfunded entitlements for the elderly, which will (unless scaled back) result in substantially higher taxes on future generations. Click here for my views on the problem.

Today, Hillary Clinton floated a new idea: an entitlement for future generations. Here is the story:

Clinton: $5,000 for Every U.S. Baby

Democratic presidential candidate Hillary Rodham Clinton said Friday that every child born in the United States should get a $5,000 "baby bond" from the government to help pay for future costs of college or buying a home.

Clinton, her party's front-runner in the 2008 race, made the suggestion during a forum hosted by the Congressional Black Caucus.

"I like the idea of giving every baby born in America a $5,000 account that will grow over time, so that when that young person turns 18 if they have finished high school they will be able to access it to go to college or maybe they will be able to make that downpayment on their first home," she said.

The New York senator did not offer any estimate of the total cost of such a program or how she would pay for it. Approximately 4 million babies are born each year in the United States.

How might this be funded? There are only three groups that could be asked to pay for the new entitlement with higher taxes (or lower benefits): the current elderly, those currently of working age, or the same future generations who are getting the new benefit and are slated to pay for existing unfunded entitlements. Which group do you think Senator Clinton has in mind?

If any of my economist friends involved in the Clinton campaign wants to email me the answer and, more generally, the rationale for this idea, I will gladly post it for my readers.

How the Rich Got Rich

While there are 74 Forbes 400 members who inherited their entire fortune, 270 members are entirely self-made.
Source.

A Healthcare Quiz

The political issue of the hour is the debate over expanding SCHIP, the State Children's Health Insurance Program. The Washington Post calls it "the biggest domestic policy clash" of the Bush presidency.

As a bit of factual background, here is a quick quiz:

With medical costs skyrocketing, the middle class struggling, and heartless Republicans running the government, what has happened to the percentage of children without health insurance over the past seven years?
Find the answer here. Scroll down to Figure 1. Thanks to reader John Dewey for the link.

Update: David Brooks on the SCHIP debate.

Thursday, September 27, 2007

Night at the Mankiws

A contribution from guest blogger Tobin.

Economic Misconceptions

GMU economist Bryan Caplan summarizes The Four Boneheaded Biases of Stupid Voters.

Naked Self-Promotion

The Science and Art of Monetary Policy

Wednesday, September 26, 2007

How big a problem is lack of health insurance?

Dick Morris has a question for Hillary Clinton:

You base your healthcare proposal on the need to cover 47 million "uninsured Americans." Since about a third of them are illegal immigrants and another third are eligible for Medicaid right now and just don't apply for it, aren't you overstating the problem?

His one-third figures seem a bit high to me, but he is right that 47 million substantially overestimates the magnitude of the problem. A serious estimate would take out both illegal immigrants and those who are eligible for Medicaid but have not applied. Those eligible for Medicaid can always enroll once they need significant medical care.

In addition, I would exclude those who were offered employer-provided health insurance but declined coverage, and those that are healthy and making more than, say, $50,000 a year. These two groups are choosing to roll the dice. According to estimates I have seen, they make up more than a quarter of the uninsured.*

What is the right figure for the number of Americans who do not have access to health insurance? I don't know, but it is much less than 47 million. If anyone knows of a reliable estimate, let me know.

* See the Economic Report of the President, 2004, page 197.

Plosser: Inflation Hawk

It sounds like Philadelphia Fed President Charlie Plosser is not inclined to cut rates much further.

He’s Happier, She’s Less So

David Leonhardt describes the latest in happiness research from economists Alan Krueger, Betsey Stevenson, and Justin Wolfers (all of whom have PhDs from the Harvard economics department).

Am I a typo?

Tuesday, September 25, 2007

A Jump in Expected Inflation

Jim Hamilton, one of the most astute macroeconomist-bloggers, provides this great graphic. It shows forward inflation compensation during the market trading of Tuesday last week. This measure is based on the spread between nominal bond yields and real (inflation-protected) bond yields. It reflects the market's expectation of future inflation--to be precise, the expectation of the average five-year inflation rate starting five years from now. Click through to the Hamilton link for more details if you are not familiar with this sort of data.

The jump upward at 2 pm occurred just after the Fed's announcement of a surprisingly large cut in its target interest rate. The apparent change in expected inflation is not large--about 5 basis points--but it is striking nonetheless. It shows clearly how easier monetary policy raises expected inflation.

Obama on Social Security

Barack Obama suggests a plan to fix Social Security:
I do not want to cut benefits or raise the retirement age. I believe there are a number of ways we can make Social Security solvent that do not involve placing these added burdens on our seniors. One possible option, for example, is to raise the cap on the amount of income subject to the Social Security tax. If we kept the payroll tax rate exactly the same but applied it to all earnings and not just the first $97,500, we could virtually eliminate the entire Social Security shortfall.
This seems to be a shift from his past statements and puts him closer to Senator Clinton.

Under this plan, the top marginal tax rate (including federal income and payroll taxes, but not state taxes) would rise from 37.9 to 50.3 percent.

Correction: The first comment points out that my calculation was not quite right:
To correctly count the employer's 7.65% of payroll taxes as a marginal tax (and it is), we have to also include it as income. Thus, for someone in the 35% tax bracket who earns an extra $1 in income, pays 7.65% in payroll taxes and whose employer pays 7.65% in payroll taxes, the true marginal tax rate is:(.35 + .0765 +.0765)/(1+.0765) = 46.7. I wouldn't want to pay 46.7% or 50.3% as a marginal tax, but we need to be honest on this issue.

The Social Security Challenge

The U.S. Treasury released a report yesterday called Social Security Reform: The Nature of the Problem. Here is the summary:
  • Social Security faces a shortfall over the indefinite future of $13.6 trillion in present value terms, an amount equal to 3.5 percent of future taxable payrolls. Looking at the gap over a shorter horizon provides only limited information on the financial status of the program.
  • Social Security can be made permanently solvent only by reducing the present value of scheduled benefits and/or increasing the present value of scheduled tax revenues. Other changes to the program might be desirable, but only these changes can restore solvency permanently.
  • Delaying changes to Social Security reduces the number of cohorts over which the burden of reform can be spread. Not taking action is thus unfair to future generations. This is a significant cost of delay.
  • By itself, faster economic growth will not solve Social Security’s financial imbalance—realistically, there is no way to “grow out of the problem.”

Monday, September 24, 2007

A Reading for the Pigou Club

Here is supply-side guru Arthur Laffer together with coauthor Wayne Winegarden:

Of the two primary policies being proposed to address global warming—the capping and trading of emissions and the taxation of emissions—we favor the taxation of emissions. We suggest that a pro-active environmental policy should include an appropriate carbon tax fully offset by a static dollar-for-dollar across-the-board reduction in marginal income tax rates. If implemented with taxpayer protections, this policy would mitigate many if not all of the adverse economic costs from reducing carbon emissions.

Summers on Moral Hazard

Larry makes the case for bailouts. This is a topic on which there is little consensus among professional economists. Larry represents the more activist point of view.

In the process of making some general points, Larry defends the 1990s bailouts he was involved with:
A competent lender of last resort – in Bagehot’s sense of one who lends freely at a penalty rate against good collateral – actually turns a profit, as the IMF did in its response to the financial crises of the 1990s.
The fact that this particular bailout was profitable ex post is, however, scant evidence that it was wise ex ante. In particular:
An important corollary to recognizing that decisions are about probabilities is that decisions should not be judged by outcomes but by the quality of the decision-making, though outcomes are certainly one useful input in that evaluation.. Any individual decisions can be badly thought through, and yet be successful.
That piece of wisdom, by the way, is from Robert Rubin.

Larry concludes with some general guidelines for when bailouts are okay:
First, are there substantial contagion effects? Second, is the problem a liquidity problem where a contribution to stability can be provided with high probability or does it involve problems of solvency? Third, is it reasonable to expect that the action in question will not impose costs on taxpayers? If the answers to all three questions are affirmative, there is a strong case for public action.
These questions are sensible, but they are hardly an algorithm for good policy. They are extraordinarily vague, leaving a lot of discretion to those in power.

Bailout critics are skeptical that government policymakers are likely to have all the wisdom that Larry presumes. And they are skeptical that those who oversaw the "successful" bailouts of the 1990s were actually as wise as they think they were. After all, "individual decisions can be badly thought through, and yet be successful."

Sunday, September 23, 2007

Goolsbee on Real Estate

Austan Goolsbee tells you how to sell your house.

Saturday, September 22, 2007

Helicopter Ben

The "dropping money from a helicopter" thought experiment has become associated with Ben Bernanke, who once used it in a speech. But of course it was not original to him: The thought experiment is a very old one within monetary economics and is typically credited to Milton Friedman.

Thanks to Luskin for the image.

The Rules of the Game

Free market economies succeed by virtue of competition. But what rules should govern that competition? A producer in a market can put another producer out of business by making a better product but not by burning down his factory. That much seems obvious. Sometimes, however, it is harder to determine what the rules should be.

A fascinating example is unfolding at Harvard. The Coop is the university-affiliated bookstore, which stocks textbooks for courses (and I believe is run by Barnes and Noble). The store called the cops when some students who operate a bookselling website started copying down prices and ISBN numbers and then refused to leave when asked.

Was the Coop in the right? After all, the Coop is private property, and perhaps it should be able to regulate behavior on its premises and exclude anyone it wants. On the other hand, the Coop opens itself to the public, and the students were only examining merchandise it was offering for sale.

Which side would you take, if you were setting the rules of the game?

Friday, September 21, 2007

Life after Ec 10

I happened to notice that Kenneth Griffin is on the latest list of the Forbes 400 richest Americans with net worth of $3 billion (at age 38). Griffin was a graduate of Harvard College and, according to Wikipedia, an economics major.

Yes, I know, the Harvard econ department does not deserve all the credit for Mr Griffin's success, but we will happily accept a small share of it. After all, our building does need renovation.

Thursday, September 20, 2007

Jon Stewart is a Genius

Jon Stewart asks Alan Greenspan an excellent question:

Why do we have a Fed? Why do we have someone adjusting the rates if we’re a free-market society?
Alan's answer is not satisfying, but I don't blame him: The economics profession does not have a good answer.

We economists have rigorous and fundamental theory to explain why we have environmental regulation (externalities) and to explain why we have antitrust laws (market power), but there is no consensus about what market failure calls for the existence of a central bank. The answer has something to do with the benefits of a system of fiat money. And it has something to do with the possibility of short-run monetary nonneutrality (due to sticky prices and/or imperfect information about prices). But the precise combination of elements that would yield a satisfying answer is still elusive.

Stewart stumbled upon a fundamental question of monetary economics. If anyone has a good answer, let me know, or publish it in the American Economic Review.

DeLong on Greenspan

Brad DeLong reviews Alan Greenspan's new book. (Free registration required.)

A Question for Democrats

Okay, you want to raise taxes on the rich. I get that. But what do you want to do with the money?

At different times, it seems, you want to
  1. Fund universal health care.
  2. Give a tax cut to the middle class.
  3. Reduce the long-term fiscal gap.
Which is it?

To get some idea about the numbers involved here, let's turn to the Congressional Budget Office. The CBO tells us that each percentage-point increase in the top two income tax rates (singles making over about $150K, married taxpayers over about $180K) increases tax revenue by only about $6 billion a year. And even that $6 billion is an overestimate, because it takes into account only a limited range of behavioral responses to higher tax rates.

No one really thinks you can achieve all three of the above goals in any significant degree and pay for them with only tax hikes on the rich. When it comes down to choosing among the three goals, which one would you pick?

Another Convert

From an email this morning:
After nearly two years as your reader, you've pretty much singlehandedly made me a fiscal libertarian out of a former democratic socialist.

Wednesday, September 19, 2007

Politicizing Monetary Policy

My recommendation to members of Congress: No more press releases like this one.

The last thing we need is the perception that the Fed is caving in to political pressure. Such a perception, even if unfounded, would raise inflation expectations and make the Fed's job even harder.

Lucas on Monetary Policy

In today's Wall Street Journal (subscription required), Robert Lucas opines on the Fed. An excerpt:

Mortgages and Monetary Policy
By Robert E. Lucas, Jr.

In the past 50 years, there have been two macroeconomic policy changes in the United States that have really mattered. One of these was the supply-side reduction in marginal tax rates, initiated after Ronald Reagan was elected president in 1980 and continued and extended during the current administration. The other was the advent of "inflation targeting," which is the term I prefer for a monetary policy focused on inflation-control to the exclusion of other objectives. As a result of these changes, steady GDP growth, low unemployment rates and low inflation rates -- once thought to be an impossible combination -- have been a reality in the U.S. for more than 20 years....

The need for a lender-of-last-resort function is one qualification to the discipline of inflation targeting, but it is a necessary one. There is a second line of argument that seems to me much less compelling. It starts with the fact that monetary policy necessarily affects future inflation rates, not the current rate: That has already been determined when the open market committee meets. We also know that whatever funds rate target is chosen, all kinds of others forces -- anything that happens to the real economy -- will affect next quarter's rate of inflation, or next year's. So we would like to forecast these other forces as well as possible and take them into account.

There is nothing wrong with this logic, but how useful it is depends on how good we are at forecasting the non-monetary determinants of prices. In fact, inflation forecasting is notoriously one of the squishiest areas of economic statistics. In this situation, it is all too easy for easy money advocates to see a recession coming and rationalize low interest rates. They could be right -- who really knows? -- and in any case we may not know enough to prove them wrong.

So I am skeptical about the argument that the subprime mortgage problem will contaminate the whole mortgage market, that housing construction will come to a halt, and that the economy will slip into a recession. Every step in this chain is questionable and none has been quantified. If we have learned anything from the past 20 years it is that there is a lot of stability built into the real economy.

To me, inflation targeting at its best is an application of Milton Friedman's maxim that "inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon," and its corollary that monetary policy should concentrate on the one thing it can do well -- control inflation. It can be hard to keep this in mind in financially chaotic times, but I think it is worth a try.

Tuesday, September 18, 2007

Hubbard and Cogan on Healthcare

Glenn Hubbard and John Cogan want to bring the market to healthcare.

Elmendorf on the Subprime Problem


Brookings economist Doug Elmendorf (who long ago was head section leader for ec 10) offers his Notes on Policy Responses to the Subprime Mortgage Unraveling.

Schumpeter and Galbraith

Bernanke on the Great Depression

Monday, September 17, 2007

Meltzer on Monetary Policy

Allan Meltzer takes on Martin Feldstein and says the Fed should hold firm.

Merit Pay

James Miller, an economist at Smith College, has an intriguing proposal:
institutions should empower graduating seniors to reward teaching excellence. Colleges should do this by giving each graduating senior $1,000 to distribute among their faculty.
Newmark's Door worries that this would encourage inflated grades and dumbed down courses.

The Maestro

Here's Alan Greenspan on the economy of the future.

Sunday, September 16, 2007

The Pigou Club Manifesto II

In today's NY Times, I make the case for a carbon tax.

Super Crunchers

David Leonhardt gives a mixed review to Ian Ayres's new book Super Crunchers.

Saturday, September 15, 2007

UC Davis should be ashamed of itself

A reader emails me this story:
After a group of UC Davis women faculty began circulating a petition, UC regents rescinded an invitation to Larry Summers, the controversial former president of Harvard University, to speak at a board dinner Wednesday night in Sacramento.
If there is any place that should be open to a wide range of views, it is a university. To bar a scholar as prominent as Larry from talking simply because you disagree with him is despicable.

Order and Disorder

Friday, September 14, 2007

Raj Chetty

Free Market Hall of Fame

Cast your vote here.

Hanson vs Cutler

Economists Robin Hanson and David Cutler debate health care.

Thursday, September 13, 2007

Google-Scholar vs SSCI

Magnus Henrekson and Daniel Waldenström consider various ways of ranking academic economists.

One tidbit from their table 4: The Spearman rank correlation between cites in Google-Scholar and cites in the Social Science Citation Index is 0.848. In other words, the newer Google-Scholar yields very similar conclusions to the more conventional source for citation data.

A Secret Rate Cut?

Robert Barro emails me:

Did you know that the average Fed Funds rate for August was 5.0%? That is, the Fed already cut rates by a quarter point--it just did not announce it.
He is right: The intended Federal Funds rate is still at 5.25, but the actual rate was 5.02 in August.

In the preceding 13 months, the Fed missed its target by no more than a single basis point. But then in August it misses by 23 basis points. Why? Is this an unannounced change in the target, or is the Fed getting worse at hitting its target?

Wednesday, September 12, 2007

A Cross-elasticity Surprise

A reader calls my attention to new research on gas prices:

A causal relationship between gasoline prices and obesity is possible through mechanisms of increased exercise and decreased eating in restaurants. I use a fixed effects model to explore whether this theory has empirical support, finding that an additional $1 in real gasoline prices would reduce obesity in the U.S. by 15% after five years, and that 13% of the rise in obesity between 1979 and 2004 can be attributed to falling real gas prices during this period.

What should the fed funds rate be?

Martin Feldstein says
The time has come for the Federal Reserve to cut the federal funds interest rate substantially, starting on a path from the current 5.25% to 4.25% and possibly even less.
My favorite equation for monetary policy predicts a somewhat smaller rate cut.

Bernanke on National Saving

A smart economist emails me a question about the Fed chairman's most recent talk:

I'm wondering what your reaction is to Ben's latest "global savings glut" speech.

Ben's conjecture that real interest rates have fallen as a result of increased saving among emerging and oil producing countries seems plausible to me. What strikes me as off kilter, though, is the normative conclusion he draws, that the current account deficit therefore poses a problem of insufficient savings domestically. Arguments for insufficient saving often have as starting point myopic or otherwise irrational behavior by savers. But it's entirely rational for people to save less when real interest rates fall. If a global savings glut has driven down real rates, US savers are worse off as a result, but a policy response of encouraging more saving would only exacerbate the domestic welfare loss stemming from the glut.

What, if anything, am I missing here?
I agree that Ben has not fully spelled out his logic on this point. Even our current account deficit is the result of a "saving glut" abroad, that is no reason by itself that Americans should save more.

Nonetheless, many economists agree with Ben's normative conclusion that U.S. national saving should increase. One might argue national saving is too low because the tax code discourages saving (as my colleague Martin Feldstein would emphasize), because people suffer from problems of self control (as my colleague David Laibson would emphasize), or because the U.S. government is not saving enough to deal with the coming entitlement crunch. My guess is that Ben would have sympathy for all three arguments.

Tuesday, September 11, 2007

The Inequality Debate

Are America's Rich Falling Behind The Super-Rich?

Thanks to Ron Cronovich for the pointer.

Harvard Profs on the Fed

The Harvard Crimson interviews several Harvard economics professors about monetary policy. Before reading the article, guess which two of them offered these assessments:
“The most important thing [the Fed] does is respond to major financial crises,... Inflation is OK right now, and the economy is weakening...I think he should lower [the target for the Federal funds rate].”

“The subprime event is not that big a deal. It’s a small part of the economy. There will be some foreclosures, banks will lose money. That’s life. That’s capitalism. They took risks, and they lost. Policy should not bail out people for greed and stupidity, or their risk taking.”

Monday, September 10, 2007

The End of an Era


The RTE blog reports that Martin Feldstein is stepping down as President of the NBER. Here is his resignation letter.

Sunday, September 09, 2007

Pigou Club T-shirts

Available here.

Disclaimer: I have no knowledge about, or financial interest in, this supplier.

Boys will be boys

Some new research on gender and education, via Tim Harford:
A new working paper from economists Victor Lavy of Hebrew University and Analía Schlosser of Princeton attempts to unpick the peer effects associated with gender, using data on nearly half a million students passing through Israel's school system in the 1990s. They compared consecutive year groups passing through the same school, figuring that if one year's group was 55 percent boys and the next year's was 55 percent girls, that difference was very likely to be random and thus susceptible to meaningful number crunching. Their answer chimes perfectly with the conventional wisdom: Boys benefit from being in a classroom with girls, but girls do not benefit from being in a classroom with boys.

Clinton vs Obama

The Wall Street Journal (subscription required) reports:

Sen. Hillary Rodham Clinton told an AARP convention that, as president, she would move quickly to fix Social Security's long-term finances, but that cutting benefits or raising the eligibility age would be "off the table." That would leave only higher payroll taxes as a solution, most experts say.

The New York Democrat's comments, made in Boston on Friday, were a further effort to draw distinctions with her chief rival for her party's presidential nomination, Illinois Sen. Barack Obama. In May, Mr. Obama said that "everything should be on the table," including benefits and taxes.

Recall that 77.2 percent of economists agree that "the best way to deal with Social Security's long-term funding gap is to increase the normal retirement age."

Saturday, September 08, 2007

A Reading for the Pigou Club

Recession Coming?

According to the betting over at intrade, the probability of a recession in 2008 is now greater than 50 percent.

Friday, September 07, 2007

Glaeser on the Mortgage Problem

Sensible solutions to the lending mess, according to my Harvard colleague Ed Glaeser.

The LIBOR Puzzle

At a conference dinner last night, a prominent economist posed the following puzzle: Over the past month, the Fed funds rate is unchanged (and is expected to fall), the discount rate is down, and the Treasury bill rate is down, but the LIBOR rate is up. Why?

A related question: We usually evaluate the stance of monetary policy with the Fed funds rate. But when LIBOR and Fed funds become unhinged, as they seem to be now, on what basis are we to choose between them?

No definitive resolutions were offered. Post your answers in the comments section.

The Mismeasurement of Science

In Current Biology, a zoologist says it is misguided to evaluate scientists by counting their citations. Fortunately, we economists would never make that mistake.

Thursday, September 06, 2007

Immigration and the Poverty Rate

Robert Samuelson argues that the U.S. poverty rate has remained as high as it is simply because many poor Hispanics have immigrated here:

Consider: From 1990 to 2006, the number of poor Hispanics increased 3.2 million, from 6 million to 9.2 million. Meanwhile, the number of non-Hispanic whites in poverty fell from 16.6 million (poverty rate: 8.8 percent) in 1990 to 16 million (8.2 percent) in 2006. Among blacks, there was a decline from 9.8 million in 1990 (poverty rate: 31.9 percent) to 9 million (24.3 percent) in 2006. White and black poverty has risen somewhat since 2000 but is down over longer periods.

Only an act of willful denial can separate immigration and poverty. The increase among Hispanics must be concentrated among immigrants, legal and illegal, as well as their American-born children. Yet, this story goes largely untold.
Of course, many of these poor immigrants are nonetheless richer than they were in their country of origin.

I wonder: How much has immigration, via this direct change in the population distribution, affected statistics like median household income?

Wednesday, September 05, 2007

Robert Barro

Ned Gramlich

Bloomberg reports that the prominent economist and policymaker Ned Gramlich has died.

Thank you, Megan...

A Reading for the Pigou Club

In today's NY Times, David Leonhardt tells us what John Dingell is really up to.

Tuesday, September 04, 2007

How much cash to hold

Bryan Caplan asks about how much money he should hold in his wallet:

At a recent GMU lunch, two economists sparred over the optimal quantity of cash to keep in one's wallet. Economist A holds very little cash, on the grounds that you can pay for virtually everything with credit cards. Economist B holds lots of cash, on the grounds that the foregone interest is virtually nothing, and his time is very valuable.

Whose side do you take, and why? Value of time and foregone interest calculations are welcome.

P.S. Please don't repeat the textbook model of money demand. I'm asking for a concrete solution, not a general framework. :-)

Bryan dismisses the textbook model too quickly. The standard Baumol-Tobin model of cash management gives more than a general framework: It yields a concrete answer. A problem in chapter 18 of my intermediate macro textbook asks the student to apply the model to a simple numerical example describing his or her own behavior.

For example, suppose that the GMU economist spends $10 per day in cash, takes 10 minutes to go get cash out of his ATM, has a value of time equal to $60 an hour, and earns 5 percent annual interest on balances held at his bank. From this information, the Baumol-Tobin model yields a very specific prediction: The prof should take out $1200 from his bank three times a year and hold an average of $600 in his wallet. (See the textbook for the equations that back up this inference.)

Most people hold much less money on average and go to the ATM much more often than the model predicts for their parameter values. This is a puzzle. It is also a great example to work through in an intermediate macro class. You can generate a good classroom discussion about why the model fails to match behavior.

One possible answer is that people are worried about losing the money. A probability p of loss or theft would affect the opportunity cost of holding cash and thus effectively raise the interest rate that enters the model to r+p. But plugging in numbers makes this a hard case to make. To match behavior, such as a biweekly trip to the ATM, you would need people to lose their wallets far more often than they do.

Many students will then say that they don't hold as much cash as the model predicts because they are afraid they will spend it. This response raises an intriguing behavioral theory: Money burns a hole in your pocket, but the temptation is somehow removed if the money is left at the bank. I don't find this very compelling as a description of my own behavior, but my experience is that many students are more attracted to it.

Rogoff on the Fed (and on Marriage)

Ken Rogoff discusses monetary policy and asset prices. His conclusion:
In a sense, a central bank's relationship with asset markets is like that of a man who claims he is going to the ballet to make himself happy, not to make his wife happy. But then he sheepishly adds that if his wife is not happy, he cannot be happy.

Monday, September 03, 2007

Job Market Rumor Mill

If you are a new econ PhD on the job market this year, this rumor mill will help you find and share information (and reach the requisite level of anxiety).

Economic Disaster 101

Sunday, September 02, 2007

House Prices in the Taylor Rule?

Rick Mishkin seems to think that house prices should be added to the Taylor rule:

Central bankers should ease monetary policy quickly and aggressively in response to a big fall in house prices, Federal Reserve governor Frederic Mishkin said on Saturday.

Presenting a paper on the final day of the Fed’s Jackson Hole symposium, Mr Mishkin said policymakers should not wait until output falls, but should “react immediately to the house price decline when they see it.”

He said the optimal policy response was both quicker and more aggressive than that suggested by a standard policy rule, in which policymakers respond only to deviations in output and inflation.

He said simulations show that this approach “can be very successful at counteracting the real effects” of even a large house price slump, because of the long lags from changes in housing wealth to changes in consumer spending.

From the FT.

Update: Here is the Mishkin paper.

Traffic Citations as a Revenue Source

Via Judy Chevalier:
tickets were issued more often in places that were short on cash, and out-of-towners received tickets more often than drivers with local addresses.

Saturday, September 01, 2007

The Laibson Plan to End Mortgage Insanity

My Harvard colleague David Laibson (via Justin Fox) has a proposal for dealing with unscrupulous mortgage lenders:
To prevent lending institutions from offering misleading deals that trap borrowers, we should require that all future mortgage loans be prepayable with no penalty. This is an easy, simple rule. The rule will have the effect of leading banks to stop offering many of the teaser rates that serve as loss leaders (pay too little interest for the first 18 months but then pay extra on the back end). These loss leaders are often confusing and tempting for borrowers. Banks won't want to offer loss leaders if borrowers can get out of the loan without paying a penalty after the subsidized payment period -- the teaser period -- ends.

My proposal would not discourage banks from offering sensible adjustable rate mortgages (those without a loss leader component). Borrowers should be allowed to take out a mortgage pegged to short-term rates. That's not a loss leader and such mortgages will still be offered if prepayment is made penalty-free. My proposal will only hit the mortgages with early loss leaders built into the payment stream.
I appreciate the logic here. When I refinanced my mortgage not long ago, one of my first questions was, Are there any prepayment penalties? I figured that as long as the answer was no, I was less likely to be hit with strange, hidden provisions down the road.